We are independent & ad-supported. We may earn a commission for purchases made through our links.

Advertiser Disclosure

Our website is an independent, advertising-supported platform. We provide our content free of charge to our readers, and to keep it that way, we rely on revenue generated through advertisements and affiliate partnerships. This means that when you click on certain links on our site and make a purchase, we may earn a commission. Learn more.

How We Make Money

We sustain our operations through affiliate commissions and advertising. If you click on an affiliate link and make a purchase, we may receive a commission from the merchant at no additional cost to you. We also display advertisements on our website, which help generate revenue to support our work and keep our content free for readers. Our editorial team operates independently from our advertising and affiliate partnerships to ensure that our content remains unbiased and focused on providing you with the best information and recommendations based on thorough research and honest evaluations. To remain transparent, we’ve provided a list of our current affiliate partners here.

What is Prospect Theory?

By Danielle DeLee
Updated Jan 22, 2024
Our promise to you
WiseGeek is dedicated to creating trustworthy, high-quality content that always prioritizes transparency, integrity, and inclusivity above all else. Our ensure that our content creation and review process includes rigorous fact-checking, evidence-based, and continual updates to ensure accuracy and reliability.

Our Promise to you

Founded in 2002, our company has been a trusted resource for readers seeking informative and engaging content. Our dedication to quality remains unwavering—and will never change. We follow a strict editorial policy, ensuring that our content is authored by highly qualified professionals and edited by subject matter experts. This guarantees that everything we publish is objective, accurate, and trustworthy.

Over the years, we've refined our approach to cover a wide range of topics, providing readers with reliable and practical advice to enhance their knowledge and skills. That's why millions of readers turn to us each year. Join us in celebrating the joy of learning, guided by standards you can trust.

Editorial Standards

At WiseGeek, we are committed to creating content that you can trust. Our editorial process is designed to ensure that every piece of content we publish is accurate, reliable, and informative.

Our team of experienced writers and editors follows a strict set of guidelines to ensure the highest quality content. We conduct thorough research, fact-check all information, and rely on credible sources to back up our claims. Our content is reviewed by subject matter experts to ensure accuracy and clarity.

We believe in transparency and maintain editorial independence from our advertisers. Our team does not receive direct compensation from advertisers, allowing us to create unbiased content that prioritizes your interests.

Prospect theory is an economic theory of behavior that attempts to explain people’s decisions when they are faced with situations that involve risk. According to the theory, people evaluate potential gains and losses as changes from their current state rather than as independent situations in the future, and they try to avoid losses more than they try to seek winnings. People perceive the likelihood of an event inaccurately, especially when the probability is close to zero or one. Prospect theory explains seemingly irrational decisions in situations like gambling and insurance purchases.

In a 1979 paper titled “Prospect Theory,” published in Econometrica, Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky outlined the theory. The proposal of prospect theory was instrumental in the foundation of a new field: behavioral economics. This field of study blends principles of economics and psychology. In 2002, Kahneman shared the Nobel Prize in Economics with Vernon L. Smith for their work in establishing the field.

Most economic theory is descriptive; that is, it seeks to explain human behavior through the use of simplifying models. If the real world does not exhibit the behavior that a model predicts, then it is the model that needs to be revised. This was the case with expected utility theory, which predicted that people would accurately assess probabilities and payoffs to make a rational choice in the face of risk. This means that a person should be indifferent between a 50 percent chance of winning 1,000 and a guaranteed payment of 500. An experiment run by Maurice Allais, a French economist, in 1953 cast doubt on expected utility theory.

The experiment posed a series of choices between lotteries, and respondents chose which set of payoffs and probabilities they preferred. Allais found that respondents did not always choose the lotteries that expected utility theory predicted, and his findings became known as the Allais Paradox. Kahneman and Tversky ran a variation of the Allais experiment and obtained similar results. For example, the majority of respondents preferred a guaranteed payoff of 3,000 to an 80 percent chance of receiving 4,000, even though the second option has an expected value that is 200 higher than the expected value of the first.

Kahneman and Tversky attempted to explain the Allais Paradox by examining human decision-making processes. They proposed that each economic agent, or person making an economic decision, has two functions relevant to decisions in the face of risk: the value function and the decision weight function. When calculating his expected utility, the agent uses the payoffs and probabilities from these functions rather than the stated numbers when deciding between lotteries.

The value function assigns a value to a payoff. Unlike the predictions of expected utility theory, the magnitude of negative and positive payoffs is not the same — the negative portion of the value function is steeper than the positive portion, so the absolute value of a loss is greater than the absolute value of an equivalent win. This is where prospect theory gets its name: the agent views each lottery as a prospect for change from his current position. In the case of a guaranteed 300 versus a 50 percent chance of winning 1,000 and a 50 percent chance of losing 400, expected utility theory would say that the lotteries are equivalent because they both have an expected value of 300. Under prospect theory, the potential loss of 400 might outweigh the potential gain of 1,000, so the agent could strongly prefer the guaranteed 300.

The weighting function describes how agents treat probabilities. Under expected utility theory, agents multiply the payoff by the exact probability of its occurrence. Prospect theory recognizes that agents have an imperfect grasp of the meaning of probabilities. The weighting function describes the probability that agents use in their calculations, or the decision weight, for each level of stated probability. The decision weight tends to be lower than the stated probability except at the ends of the function: agents treat probabilities that are close to zero as zero, treat small probabilities as larger than they really are and treat probabilities close to 100 percent as certainties.

Prospect theory applies to any situation in which agents must make a decision based on the evaluation of payoffs and probabilities. Agents might buy insurance when the premium is higher than the expected value of their potential losses since they tend to overestimate small probabilities. Similarly, they might overestimate the chance of winning the lottery and buy tickets that, on average, do not pay off. This theory allows economists to evaluate the reasoning behind these decisions rather than writing them off as irrational.

WiseGeek is dedicated to providing accurate and trustworthy information. We carefully select reputable sources and employ a rigorous fact-checking process to maintain the highest standards. To learn more about our commitment to accuracy, read our editorial process.

Discussion Comments

By donasmrs — On Apr 28, 2014

@fBoyle-- I'm not sure if we could say that, but we can say that human rationality and economic rationality are different things. Something that is economically rational may not seem rational according to the human mind.

Although some people averse risk and some seek risk, it's difficult to predict what people will choose to do because there is more than one factor affecting their decision. For example, it depends on an individual's present position and the monetary amounts that are involved.

By fBoyle — On Apr 27, 2014

This is very interesting. Based on the prospect theory, can we say that humans are pessimists? Do we exaggerate losses and underestimate gains?

By fify — On Apr 26, 2014

It's kind of surprising that the prospect theory was thought of in 1979. Since the 2000s, it's widely known now that individuals do not always make accurate or realistic decisions. When we are faced with options, we often choose the option that is less beneficial for us because of thought fallacies.

The fallacy that causes someone to choose the option that has less gains is similar to the fallacy that makes someone think that something is a better buy because it is ninety nine cents rather than one dollar. People make wrong decisions every day.

I personally think that this has to do with a subconscious fear of losing. That fear is so powerful that we would rather win less than lose less. The human mind loves certainties, it does not like probabilities, just like our desire to know what the future holds for us. Our mind wants stability and security, and probabilities don't fit in with that mindset.

WiseGeek, in your inbox

Our latest articles, guides, and more, delivered daily.

WiseGeek, in your inbox

Our latest articles, guides, and more, delivered daily.